Showing posts with label Law. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Law. Show all posts

Tuesday, January 12, 2010

Olson Goes to China

The legal world is abuzz with Ted Olson's testimonial on behalf of gay marriage in Newsweek as Perry v. Schwarzenegger kicks off in federal court. He and David Boies, who faced off in Bush v. Gore in 2000, are joining forces to make the case that Proposition 8 is, in essence, unconstitutional.

It's a stunning argument, and shows why the former Bush administration Solicitor General is among the top barristers in the country. It's safe to say that if Olson wins this case before the Supreme Court, he'll secure for himself a place among the top barristers in American history, alongside Daniel Webster, not just John Roberts.

I have little to add to this story that others cannot with greater sophistication; for now, it may be helpful to bookend Olson's Newsweek turn with this NY Times profile from August 2009, which includes this interesting nugget from Robert Bork:

Conservative colleagues are kinder, but many remain bewildered. Former Judge Robert H. Bork, a close friend who has called same-sex marriage a “judicial sin,” said he could not bear to speak to Mr. Olson about the case.

“I don’t want to get into an argument,” Mr. Bork said. “But I’d like to know why.”


From a critical legal studies perspective, Olson and Co. are likely counting on the votes of Breyer, Sotomayor, Stevens and Ginsburg. It takes one more vote, and that vote would likely come from Anthony Kennedy, who wrote the majority opinion in each of Romer v. Evans, the 1996 case that invalidated a Colorado constitutional amendment on the basis that it violated rational basis scrutiny under the Equal Protection Clause and Lawrence v. Texas, the 2003 case that invalidated state laws against same-sex sodomy on the basis of substantive due process (for non-lawyers, essentially a sister doctrine of equal protection).

We can't probe Justice Kennedy's brain, but two takeaway points from Lawrence may show where this is headed:

In her concurrence, then-Justice Sandra Day O'Connor argued that the sodomy law not only violated the Due Process Clause, but violated the Equal Protection Clause under a rational-basis scrutiny -- i.e., that there wasn't a reasonable relationship to a legitimate government interest). (Incidentally, I'd be fascinated in the takes of both retired Justice O'Connor and Justice Souter on this case).

In his dissent, Justice Scalia argued as follows:

The Texas statute undeniably seeks to further the belief of its citizens that certain forms of sexual behavior are “immoral and unacceptable"... the same interest furthered by criminal laws against fornication, bigamy, adultery, adult incest, bestiality, and obscenity.... The Texas statute, [the majority] says, “furthers no legitimate state interest which can justify its intrusion into the personal and private life of the individual."....

This effectively decrees the end of all morals legislation. If, as the Court asserts, the promotion of majoritarian sexual morality is not even a legitimate state interest, none of the above-mentioned laws can survive rational-basis review.


Scalia is prescient in at least this regard -- presumably, under the Lawrence reasoning, Prop 8 and referenda and state laws like it could be rendered unconstitutional without even so much as proclaiming gays and lesbians as a protected class, and it's really just a jurisprudential baby step from Lawrence.

Saturday, January 9, 2010

54-40 or Coase?


Economics scholars (as well as students in property law in US law school programs) are familiar with the Coase Theorem.


The Coase Theorem states that in a world of zero transactions costs and clearly defined property rights (i.e., that you can buy property with relative administrative ease and you can be certain that the property is yours after you've bought it), the efficient allocation of resources is independent of the distribution of property rights.


The Coase theorem, as one of the lynchpin ideas of the law-and-economics schools, essentially says that it doesn't matter how the legal authority -- say, a judge -- allocates the ownership of the property, only that the ownership is clearly defined. At such point, the actors, who will know definitively how property right are assigned, will be able to negotiate and bargain for rights.


Driving recently from Washington state to British Canada, I wondered if perhaps nations act under a somewhat similar principle. Specifically, I began to wonder if the 1849 settlement of the Oregon Country (during the single term of James K. Polk, perhaps the most under-appreciated antebellum US president) served as the "legal allocation" allowing American and Canadian actors to settle in earnest what would become Seattle and Vancouver. Seattle's creation dates to 1851; Vancouver's incorporation was in 1866.


To be sure, there are other contemporary historical elements propelling the growth of Pacific Northwest cities -- various gold rushes, beginning with California's 1848 gold rush, as well as the general westward expansionary push. Certainly the inception of transcontinental railroads in the 1870s in both the US and Canada were a factor in the growth of Seattle and Vancouver.


Perhaps Dominion in Canada in 1867 could be identified as a secondary "Coase" moment, which, more than any other point in evolutionary Canadian history, marks the moment that Canada transformed from colony into nation-state.


An interesting question with implications for game theorists, political scientists, legal scholars and historians alike.